Friday, September 20, 2024

The €35 Billion E.U. Loan to Ukraine: One E.U. State as a Destabilizer

On September 20, 2024, it was announced that the E.U. would “raise a €35 billion loan to support the Ukrainian economy and military.”[1] At a press conference next to Ukraine’s president Zelenskyy, the E.U.’s president said, “Russia keeps targeting your civilian energy infrastructure in a blatant and vicious way to try to plunge your country in the dark.”[2] So the loan stood to impact the Ukrainian people directly and significantly. It would be a shame if the principle of unanimity in the European Council would stand in the way of the Ukrainian people being warm during the upcoming winter. This is a very tangible way for people to grasp just how real the costs are of state governments having vetoes over a significant number of E.U. competencies (i.e., enumerated powers). “The European Union is here to help you in this challenge to keep the lights on, to keep your people warm as winter is just around the corner, and to keep your economy going as you fight for survival,” Von der Leyen said at the news conference.[3] Hungary’s Viktor Orbán stood in the way, however, to securing the collateral for a long enough period to render the loan (an any from the U.S. based on the collateral) secure.

The loan uses Russia’s immobilized assets as collateral, and E.U. sanctions on the assets had to be renewed every six months by unanimity. The concern was that Hungary would use its veto because it is the “most Russia-friendly” E.U. state.[4] Before the announcement, the Commission had proposed alternative asset renewal periods ranging from 36 months to five years. Tellingly, one state government announced that it would wait until after the upcoming U.S. election before considering the options. This made it difficult for the E.U. to give the U.S. legal assurance that the Russian assets in the E.U. would remain frozen—that the collateral would remain under the control of the E.U. rather than go back to Russia. Because the collateral could not be assured going forward, the U.S. Congress would have to approve funding for any American loan to Ukraine secured by the collateral in Europe. Of course, the E.U.’s own loan depended on the collateral too, so the possibility that one state government would veto an extension of the assets being frozen meant that the E.U. risked being “on the hook” should Ukraine fail to pay back the E.U.’s loan.

Incredibly, Andrew Moravcsik of Princeton University spoke at Harvard on the same day as the announcement of the E.U. loan that even though right-wing state governments in the E.U. have a loud bark, their bite is muted, meaning that in terms of government policy the impact is nil. He argued that they had to appease moderates to get enough support to have any impact on actual policy. Yet Hungary’s refusal to consider any of the longer periods to keep the Russian assets frozen in the E.U. meant that the E.U. and U.S. had to assume more risk in lending to Ukraine. One need only point to the refusal of Orbán’s government to pay the €200 million fine levied by the European Court of Justice, the E.U.’s supreme court, because the Hungarian government had violated E.U. law, and to the violation itself, plus Hungary’s threat to bus migrants to the E.U. capital, to know that the ideology of Orbán’s party was indeed having an impact in policy. This had hardly escaped the notice of the Commission and the ECJ. The implication is that the E.U. could ill-afford the principle of unanimity for any E.U. competency; Euro-skeptic ideology could indeed impact policy at the federal level—and, yes, the E.U. had a federal system even in 2024 of dual-sovereignty (hence the union was not an international organization or a “bloc”). Too much sovereignty remained with the state governments in the form of the veto that they could wield in the Council, and the harm can be seen in the possibility that Ukrainians would not have enough heat during the upcoming winter. Is collective action really so bad? Should one state be able to thwart it on ideological grounds?

I submit that the E.U.’s effort is laudatory but that the E.U. itself contains its own obstacle in continuing with the principle of unanimity in the Council that represents the states. Just imagine the impact on U.S. policies if one state could defeat a measure in the U.S. Senate. Even though the E.U. had fewer states at the time, there were too many for unanimity to be at all realistic on most matters. Empire-scale unions inevitably have states that differ from each other culturally and ideologically. Majority voting and qualified majority voting accommodate this fact, whereas the principle of unanimity does not.


1. Jorge Liboreiro, “EU to Raise €35 Billion Loan for Ukraine Using Russia’s Frozen Assets, Von der Leyen Says,” Euronews.com, September 20, 2024.
2. Ibid.
3. Ibid.
4. Ibid.

Friday, September 13, 2024

Nature Credits in the E.U.

One of benefits of the market mechanism, by which, for example, economic goods are bought and sold, is that self-interest is relied on; people don’t have to be told to buy or sell a product because it can be in their self-interest to do so if the price is right. As an alternative to regulatory standards, a government can create units of pollution-allowance that businesses can purchase so to be lawfully able to pollute in so far as a purchased unit allows. In the E.U.’s emissions trading system, “operators of power plants and factories have to buy tradeable allowances to cover every tonne of carbon dioxide they emit.”[1] Business could buy and sell allowances so as to cover the amount of pollution that is anticipated. In this way, the market mechanism efficiently allocates pollution in line both with the interests of the companies and the public interest—the latter being made concrete in the decision on how much pollution per allowance and how many allowance units to create. Crucially, the company private interests are put within the purview of the public interest; the tail is not directing the dog. In political economies in which political-campaign contributions by businesses are high, especially if unlimited, the tail can indeed wag the dog, such that the public interest is determined by private interests. This is one reason why the Citizens United (2010) U.S. Supreme Court case is so significant. It allows corporations and labor unions to spend unlimited amounts of money on political campaigns and directly on advertisements—both being beneficial to elected officials in positions to curry favor through legislation and regulations favorable to business (or labor). The informal exchanges of political donations and legislation or regulation comprise a market of sorts. So, the market mechanism, which is created or at least regulated by government, can serve for good or ill, from the standpoint of the public interest.  Using the mechanism, such as the E.U. president proposed in 2024, on behalf of ecosystems, is for good rather than ill, and thus using, in effect, the self-interest of farmers could be better than relying on regulatory requirements that farmers expend some money and effort to beef up their local ecosystems.

At a conference on September 13, 2024, a Friday, E.U. President Ursula von der Leyen said, “We need new financial tools to compensate farmers for the extra costs of sustainability and compensate them for taking care of the soil, the land, the water, and the air.”[2] The assumption is that the farmers would not otherwise do so because expending the energy and paying the costs for the externalities would not add to their profits from farming in the short or medium term. The time-value of money too reflects the penchant in human nature for immediate over delayed gratification. To extend the farmers’ “event-horizon” and broaden out their concern to include their vicinity would be the purposes of “the market-based system of ‘nature credits’,” which Von der Leyen hinted “could also be applied beyond the agricultural sector.”[3] This is part of the beauty of the market mechanism: it can be applying to various things, serving various purposes, rather than only pertaining to economic products and services.

Via “nature credits,” a water company could have the incentive as per self-interest to help to take care of a spring that that company depends on, and a fruit company would be more likely to invest in the “essential work of pollinators.”[4] That the language of long-term investment applies raises the question of why farmers in general do not do what manufacturing businesses do as a regular part of business. It would seem that making sure that a principal water source is not lost or that bees stay in the area of the fruit trees would be in the self-interest of the respective companies. Why would compensation by the government be needed to run a sustainable business?  Is the managerial perspective really so delimited that the viability of the business is not included?

Unfortunately, even by 2024, climate change was perceived by many business practitioners still as a gradual and outside process not germane to business. Johan Rockstrom of the Potsdam Institute for Climate Impact Research, said at the same conference, “I can tell you, science is clear today that the ultimate determinant, what regulates the stability of the planet, its ability to stay in a desired equilibrium state is nature.”[5] According to a journalist, Rockstrom was “suggesting that action of biodiversity and climate made sense even if purely pragmatic.”[6] If farmers didn’t yet see it as such, “nature credits” would help render biodiversity pragmatic from an agribusiness standpoint—essentially interiorizing some externalities.

To be sure, even if a private interest broadens out to include some hitherto externalities, that interest is still not the same as the interest of the whole: the public interest. It would still be important to protect the public interest from being captured by a private interest; a large company or an industry that would implicitly presume to be in charge of its own regulation by dictating legislation and regulation to sycophantic government officials should be withstood by them. Even so, expanding the practical purview of private interests is in the interest of the whole, and the market mechanism can be used to make this so.


1. Robert Hodgson, “Von der Leyen Moots ‘Nature Credits’ Market to Avert Ecosystem Collapse,” Euronews.com, September 13, 2024.
2. Ibid.
3. Ibid.
4. Ibid.
5. Ibid.
6. Ibid.

Saturday, September 7, 2024

Hungary and Texas: Busing Immigrants

Two years after the government of Texas in the U.S. began transferring migrants to other states and to Washington D.C., the government of Hungary announced that it too would bus migrants, but rather than transporting them to other states, the destination would be Brussels exclusively. Although the respective political strategies differ, the two policies both represent the same pressure point in federal systems. The cost of united action at the federal level on public policy is that the states are not as free as otherwise to manifest their respective ideological and cultural views in public policy at the state level. That federal policy or law is often a compromise between the preferences of the states means that political pressure exists not only between states, but between a given state and federal law. This is inherent to federalism because it provides benefits from united action and some ability of states to enact legislation reflecting their respective distinct dominant ideology. Enabling both is one of federalism’s best features, yet it comes with a cost in terms of political tension that is endemic rather than merely episodic. Simply put, no system of government is without drawbacks or downsides. The trick is perhaps in how to manage them so they don’t get so out of control that the federal system itself collapses. In 2024, Viktor Orbán, governor of the E.U. state of Hungary, was testing the limits much more than was Greg Abbott, governor of the U.S. state of Texas, even as Orbán was using Abbott’s playbook.

In June, 2024, the E.U.’s supreme court, the European Court of Justice, handed down a ruling ordering the E.U. state of Hungary to pay a fine of €200 million for breaking federal laws on asylum plus an additional €1 million per day until the state government passes a law conforming with the federal law.[1] Hungary’s requirement that people seeking asylum must first apply for and be granted travel permits violated the federal law requiring that all of the states have the same procedures for granting asylum. Setting up a confrontation with the high court, essentially challenging its very legitimacy, the Hungarian government “missed the first September deadline for paying the €200 million fine.[2] In fact, the state “also demanded compensation for the billions it says it has spent on border protection, including constructing fences protected by razor wire on its southern borders with Serbia and Croatia.”[3] In other word, the state government wanted to be reimbursed by the E.U. for costs incurred by the state to protect the E.U. border that runs along an edge of the state. Thus situated, Hungary is like Texas. Ideologically too, Hungary’s governor was quite similar to the governor of Texas at the time, Greg Abbott.

In fact, Vicktor Orbán likely got his idea to send illegal immigrants from his state to Brussels from Greg Abbott, who had spent more than $148 as of February 21, 2024 in putting more than 102,000 illegal immigrants on buses bound for other states and Washington, D.C.[4] Texas also spent $10 billion on law enforcement and constructing physical barriers at the U.S. border that runs along the edge of Texas, though reimbursement by the U.S. was not demanded.[5] At a news conference at the state capital Budapest, Hungary’s State Secretary Bence Rétvári accused the E.U. in 2024 of wanting to force the state to allow illegal immigrants into the state, and announced that the state government would “offer these illegal migrants, voluntarily, free of charge, one-way travel to Brussels.”[6] He made the announcement in front of a row of passenger buses that would be bound for the E.U. “headquarters in Belgium.”[7] He said, “If Brussels wants illegal migrants, Brussels can have them.”[8] Interestingly, Texas could have had the same strategy: instead of sending buses to lax states as well as to Washington, D.C., all of the buses could have dropped off their passengers at the Washington Mall—at the U.S. headquarters—as Abbott had been so critical of U.S. immigration policy.

Both cases—that of Hungary and Texas—demonstrate what can happen when state governments in a union differ on a matter of public policy not only with each other, but also from a federal policy or law. The degree of unity that is necessary for a union to continue to exist and function viably comes at the expense of ideological differences between states. This tension is endemic to federalism, as that system of government allows for cultural or ideological diversity between states and benefits to the whole that the combined forces of an empire-scale union can provide. In the E.U., the Hungarian government was quite critical in 2024 of Germany’s more lenient practice in allowing migrants to enter the state, yet at the same time the united force of the E.U. was able to give Europeans more power in resisting Russia’s invasion of Ukraine.  In the U.S., the Texan government was critical of California’s “sanctuary cities” in which illegal aliens were not arrested by state police, yet at the same time the united force of the U.S. was also able to stand up to Russia’s president’s militaristic foray into Ukraine. Both cases demonstrate federal systems that are “living and breathing,” allowing for differences between states, such as on abortion in the U.S. and social policy in the E.U., while enabling both unions to have a significant impact internationally.


1. Angela Skujins, “We Never Let Them In’: Hungary’s PM Viktor Orbán Demands New Laws Tackling Migration,” Euronews.com, September 6, 2024.
2. Ibid.
3. Ibid.
4. Sergio Martinez-Beltran, “Texas Has Spent More than $148 Million Busing Migrants to Other Parts of the Country,” The Texas Tribune, February 21, 2024.
5. Ibid.
6. Angela Skujins, “We Never Let Them In’: Hungary’s PM Viktor Orbán Demands New Laws Tackling Migration,” Euronews.com, September 6, 2024.
7. Ibid.
8. Ibid.